For this blog, I contacted three large pharmaceutical
companies and two agreed to speak about how they view antibiotic research and
development in light of real and potential incentives. This week, I will
discuss my conversation with Patrick Holmes, Head, International Policy, Pfizer
Global Policy and International Public Affairs. I have an interview with the second company scheduled for the end of this month and I will attempt to contact other
companies as well.
As you probably know, Pfizer recently put their toes back in
the antibiotics arena by purchasing the Astrazeneca assets. They therefore currently market
ceftazidime-avibactam and ceftaroline outside of North America. Mr. Holmes
explained that Pfizer looks on antibiotics and incentives like they would any
portfolio review project. For those of you uninitiated in this, the executives
and others compare risks and time to success across all therapeutic areas that
compete for resources within the company to choose the most promising projects
for funding. One key consideration in the analysis is time. Companies, including Wyeth when I was there,
often apply a discount for the increase in costs that the company expects to
incur over the years of the project including during years of marketing. This
factor includes increases in inflation as well as increases in costs of
research and development, marketing, capital expenses, and, of course, returns
to shareholders. Generally speaking, an industry cost of capital of is about 10% per year (similar to Wyeth’s)
(inflation by itself, even in health care, has recently hovered around 3%). This
means that without any other factor, by the end of 10 years, no project will
provide a return on today’s investment. Therefore, it is nonsense to apply this
to any preclinical project like, say, antibiotic discovery research, since that
timeline is 10-15 years before there will be a product.
In addition to the overwhelming discount of increasing
company costs is the discount assigned to risk of failure or, better,
probability of success. When you assume
that only 10-20% of projects entering phase I will succeed in getting to the
marketplace, anything prior to that such as discovery research projects again
seem overwhelmingly risky. What does this mean for Pfizer? In their model,
according to Mr. Holmes, antibiotic discovery research can only be supported
with very substantial pull and push incentives. As I thought about this, I realized
that, in fact, the time required for discovery research for antibiotics is no
different than would be true for any other therapeutic area. Pfizer may simply view
the scientific risk of antibiotic research to be prohibitively high. I believe
that is what Pfizer has concluded.
On the other hand, the good news is that in the presence of
a pull incentive, and perhaps with additional push incentives, antibiotics at a
phase 3 or later stage of development look promising to Pfizer. In other words, Pfizer is still an
opportunistic antibiotic supporter. But the pull incentive has to be the right
one. Which one is that? According to Mr. Holmes, their preferred pull
incentive is the transferable
exclusivity voucher where they would gain an increased time of exclusivity
to market a drug from their portfolio of their choice. There are many reasons
why this would be their preference, but a big one is that the reward could be
much higher than the $800 million to $2 billion that has been discussed by
DRIVE-AB and others. Pfizer would not be in favor of guardrails that would be
too limiting in this regard although we did not get into the specifics of what
Pfizer’s limits would be here. We did not discuss details of the hybrid market
entry rewards or the insurance models that have also been proposed. But Pfizer’s preference is clear and it fits
with my own oft-stated views.
I am disappointed with Pfizer’s view of antibiotic discovery
research as I am sure many of you will be as well. But their view is an
understandable one. Let biotech (or
rarely academia) and their funders take the risks. This will mean that push
incentives will more likely flow to biotech. If the resulting product is
appropriate, Pfizer will reward them and, Pfizer hopes, themselves. In this
way, pull incentives could actually have a trickle-down effect. Pfizer’s
approach should therefore be encouraging to biotech investors.
What about those PhRMA companies that have abandoned
antibiotics research? Of course, two of
them have come back into the fold – Roche and Sanofi. But have the likes of
Lilly, Abbott and Bristol-Myers-Squibb reconsidered antibiotic research in the
light of push and pull incentives? Lets try and find out! If anyone has
contacts in public policy departments at these companies, please let me know.
No comments:
Post a Comment