Thursday, June 16, 2016

Antibiotic Incentives - What's Missing?

In a word – training. I’m beginning to feel like a broken record.  I’ve been talking to various funding agencies about this need for 12 years now (1, 2, 3).  Either no one is home, or they think they have already addressed the problem, or they don’t believe there is a problem to address. 

Between mergers, acquisitions and frank abandonment of antibiotic research and development, there are precious few companies involved in the area anymore. While there has been an increase in funding for antibiotic discovery research in academia over the last decade, most academic researchers are poorly prepared to conduct this sort of research. At the same time, the committees that review grant proposals in the area are frequently made up, mostly, of the same academic researchers who are often unprepared to either judge or carry out the proposed research. Happily, at least during the years I was involved in reviewing proposals for the National Institutes of Health in the US, there were a few researchers from industry present who could help the committee understand the advantages and, more often, failings, of the proposals before us.  But we are a shrinking commodity. Many of us are older and retired. Many have moved on to areas of research outside of antibiotics  (you have to make a living after all).

Antibiotic discovery and development is a highly specialized endeavour.  It requires an understanding of a huge variety of topics and skills including clinical microbiology, epidemiology, biophysics, biochemistry, structural biology, pharmacology, pharmacokinetics, pharmacodynamics, animal testing, toxicology, chemical manufacturing, medical need, clinical infectious diseases and much more. While one does not have to have expertise in all these areas, you do have to have enough of an understanding to converse with the experts and to make judgements about how and whether to take compounds forward to the next step or not. This sort of breadth of knowledge and experience is found everyday within companies pursuing antibiotic discovery and development.  It is only rarely found in academia.

Where will our next generation of antibiotic hunters come from? I believe that they cannot come solely from academia as things stand today.  What I have been proposing for all these years is a training program of 3-12 months to take place within industry where all these skill sets can be found. For some reason (conflict of interest?), academia and therefore funding agencies seem unwilling to go forward with this sort of effort. Recently, a highly placed official from the NIH quipped that I should just fund these training programs out of my own pocket!  I just don't understand the reluctance here.

Who should be trained?  First – established researchers who are now or want to in the future conduct antibiotic discovery and development research. Next we should concentrate on post-doctoral training to give our new researchers the skills they need.  Finally, once we have trained mentors in place, we should focus on PhD candidates who want to make a career out of antibiotic research.

Who should fund this research?  We should!  Government should align with various companies still active in antibiotic research who have the appropriate skill sets to provide this training for academics. Private organizations such as Wellcome Trust and perhaps the Pew Charitable Trust could also take this on.



If we fail to act on this key area of need, we can offer all the incentives we want, but there will be no one left to take up the task of actually delivering the antibiotics we need.

Friday, June 3, 2016

Antibiotics - the Virtuous Cycle

I just returned from two days of DRIVE AB meetings in Amsterdam.  I am so excited that I couldn’t wait to get something in writing for the blog.

Two weeks ago, the O’Neill Commission (officially the Antimicrobial Resistance Review) released its final report.  If you haven’t read it – do it now! The report makes a number of very specific, key recommendations all of which make common sense.  They all fall under two general rubrics -
1.     Reduce the demand for antibiotics.
2.     Increase the supply of new antimicrobials active against resistant microorganisms.
These two are clearly conflicting – the paradox of the antibiotic market in a nutshell.  A new antibiotic hits the market and physicians don’t want to use it for fear of selecting for resistance too quickly. But this is what we must somehow achieve.

DRIVE AB is an effort to combat antibiotic resistance funded by the European Commission, the Innovative Medicines Initiative and EFPIA, the European version of PHRMA in the US.  DRIVE AB is founded on three principles – Access, Sustainability and Innovation. You can immediately see the similarity between the DRIVE AB goals and the O’Neill Commission report.  I look at DRIVE AB as the group that will provide more specific recommendations to various national and supranational authorities on how to implement the recommendations of the O’Neill Commission.

To me, the most exciting aspect of the DRIVE AB effort revolves around providing post-market incentives to pull companies into antibiotic R&D –a key recommendation of the O’Neill Commission.  Some have termed this de-linking with the idea that these incentive payments should alleviate the marketing pressure on the company to increase sales volumes and therefore to provoke a more rapid emergence of resistance. A significant upfront payment would address this need and resolve the paradox.  

Again – according to the O’Neill Commission - The reward would be given only based on societal priorities shaped by key medical needs. The CDC list of key resistance threats is a good starting point for these priorities. Payments should be free from political risk. The size of the reward should be linked to the value of the product to society (or to a given country). The payment would come soon after regulatory approval, but need not come all at once. Control for manufacturing, distribution, post-market research all should remain in the hands of the developer.

The DRIVE AB group discussed several models for such post-market rewards of which I would like to highlight just two. The first is called an insurance type reward. (See Rex & Outterson) John Rex’s favourite way to explain this is to compare the payment required to our need for fire extinguishers and for firemen. We buy the extinguishers and place them strategically in our homes and businesses and we pay the salaries of our firemen and firewomen even though, happily, most of us never actually have a fire. Paying for an antibiotic that we don’t actually need today, but that we might desperately need tomorrow is similar – its insurance. In the example we discussed, a collar and cap model is used for insurance payments. A government of payer provides a developer with an annual payment up to some specific volume of courses of therapy. If this volume is exceeded (the collar), the payer must provide additional payments on a per course basis.  This volume though, is capped.  If the cap volume is exceeded, the payer would pay some discounted price for additional courses of therapy. From my understanding, some variation of this is likely to occur in a couple of EU countries as soon as this fall for antibiotics recently approved in Europe.

The other model we discussed is the market entry model. In this model, the developer is paid one or more payments upfront. As in the insurance license model, the developer has a number of obligations by contract including those relating to good stewardship.



The model I personally prefer is similar to the insurance license model but where the upfront payment is on the order of say $1B given over the first 3-4 years post-approval. But where the developer is still allowed to sell units at some capped price.  This price would be enough to encourage good stewardship at the level of the user and the company would still have to abide by their good stewardship contract with the payer. I envision that the cap would increase after the first 3-4 years such that by the end of the exclusivity period, all sales would be based on whatever price the developer was charging.  This provides several advantages.  It keeps the developer’s skin in the game – its motivating.  It provides for a potential upside beyond the initial payment – also very motivating. And it would encourage generic manufacturers to enter the market after the period of exclusivity has expired.  The key would be to make sure that principles of stewardship and responsible end user education are maintained while actual selling the product.

The reality is that for any innovative product education will be required.  That would probably occur via some sort of medical liaison group from the developer, but would not involve “sales” representatives.

Our discussion made clear that no one model would work for any one product for all regions and no one model would fit all products for any region.  We need a choice of different post-market incentives such that various regions can choose the one that best suits their needs.

One exciting result of these incentives is the virtuous cycle. Large pharmaceutical companies like Pfizer and J&J might be motivated enough to get back into antibiotic R&D. This means that there would be more private capital to invest in academic and biotech R&D – completing a virtuous cycle leading to an even more robust antibiotic pipeline for the future.


As John Rex noted several times during the meeting – such a meeting could not have occurred even one or two years ago.  Yet here we are – at the beginning of what could be a new world.