I just
returned from two days of DRIVE AB meetings in Amsterdam. I am so excited that I couldn’t wait to get
something in writing for the blog.
Two weeks
ago, the O’Neill Commission (officially the
Antimicrobial Resistance Review) released its final report. If you haven’t read it – do it now! The
report makes a number of very specific, key recommendations all of which make
common sense. They all fall under two
general rubrics -
1. Reduce the demand for antibiotics.
2. Increase the supply of new antimicrobials
active against resistant microorganisms.
These two
are clearly conflicting – the paradox of the antibiotic market in a
nutshell. A new antibiotic hits the
market and physicians don’t want to use it for fear of selecting for resistance
too quickly. But this is what we must somehow achieve.
DRIVE AB is an effort to combat antibiotic
resistance funded by the European Commission, the Innovative Medicines
Initiative and EFPIA, the European version of PHRMA in the US. DRIVE AB is founded on three principles –
Access, Sustainability and Innovation. You can immediately see the similarity
between the DRIVE AB goals and the O’Neill Commission report. I look at DRIVE AB as the group that will
provide more specific recommendations to various national and supranational authorities
on how to implement the recommendations of the O’Neill Commission.
To me, the
most exciting aspect of the DRIVE AB effort revolves around providing
post-market incentives to pull companies into antibiotic R&D –a key
recommendation of the O’Neill Commission.
Some have termed this de-linking with the idea that these incentive
payments should alleviate the marketing pressure on the company to increase
sales volumes and therefore to provoke a more rapid emergence of resistance. A
significant upfront payment would address this need and resolve the paradox.
Again –
according to the O’Neill Commission - The reward would be given only based on
societal priorities shaped by key medical needs. The CDC list of key resistance
threats is a good starting point for these priorities. Payments should be free
from political risk. The size of the reward should be linked to the value of
the product to society (or to a given country). The payment would come soon
after regulatory approval, but need not come all at once. Control for
manufacturing, distribution, post-market research all should remain in the
hands of the developer.
The DRIVE AB
group discussed several models for such post-market rewards of which I would
like to highlight just two. The first is called an insurance type reward. (See Rex & Outterson) John Rex’s favourite way to explain this is
to compare the payment required to our need for fire extinguishers and for
firemen. We buy the extinguishers and place them strategically in our homes and
businesses and we pay the salaries of our firemen and firewomen even though,
happily, most of us never actually have a fire. Paying for an antibiotic that
we don’t actually need today, but that we might desperately need tomorrow is
similar – its insurance. In the example we discussed, a collar and cap model is
used for insurance payments. A government of payer provides a developer with an
annual payment up to some specific volume of courses of therapy. If this volume
is exceeded (the collar), the payer must provide additional payments on a per
course basis. This volume though, is
capped. If the cap volume is exceeded,
the payer would pay some discounted price for additional courses of therapy. From my understanding, some variation of
this is likely to occur in a couple of EU countries as soon as this fall for
antibiotics recently approved in Europe.
The other
model we discussed is the market entry model. In this model, the developer is
paid one or more payments upfront. As in the insurance license model, the
developer has a number of obligations by contract including those relating to
good stewardship.
The model I
personally prefer is similar to the insurance license model but where the
upfront payment is on the order of say $1B given over the first 3-4 years
post-approval. But where the developer is still allowed to sell units at some
capped price. This price would be enough
to encourage good stewardship at the level of the user and the company would
still have to abide by their good stewardship contract with the payer. I
envision that the cap would increase after the first 3-4 years such that by the
end of the exclusivity period, all sales would be based on whatever price the
developer was charging. This provides
several advantages. It keeps the developer’s
skin in the game – its motivating. It
provides for a potential upside beyond the initial payment – also very
motivating. And it would encourage generic manufacturers to enter the market
after the period of exclusivity has expired.
The key would be to make sure that principles of stewardship and
responsible end user education are maintained while actual selling the product.
The reality
is that for any innovative product education will be required. That would probably occur via some sort of
medical liaison group from the developer, but would not involve “sales” representatives.
Our
discussion made clear that no one model would work for any one product for all
regions and no one model would fit all products for any region. We need a choice of different post-market
incentives such that various regions can choose the one that best suits their
needs.
One exciting
result of these incentives is the virtuous cycle. Large pharmaceutical companies
like Pfizer and J&J might be motivated enough to get back into antibiotic
R&D. This means that there would be more private capital to invest in academic
and biotech R&D – completing a virtuous cycle leading to an even more
robust antibiotic pipeline for the future.
As John Rex
noted several times during the meeting – such a meeting could not have occurred
even one or two years ago. Yet here we
are – at the beginning of what could be a new world.
No comments:
Post a Comment